Blog dedicado ao livro A. Mateus, Economia Portuguesa, Editora Principia.

History of a crisis in one graph

The Greek crisis can best be followed by looking at the attached Figure that shows total deposits of households and non-financial corporations.

There were 3 phases in the crisis. The first, from the start of the crisis at the end of 2009, when Eurostat criticized Greece for under-estimating the Government deficit, and the Greek government requested for EU/IMF/ECB assistance in May 2010, up to June 2012 when the Samaras government takes charge with a second stabilization/aid program and with a large part of the Eurozone institutions in place to support countries in financial distress. During this period, total deposits decreased by 83.6 Billion Euros, at a rate of 2.8 Billion Euros per month. While the losses in the first half of this phase were largely due to the difficulties of stabilizing the economy and the successive delays in building an institutional framework to assist crisis countries, the second half was deeply marked by the protracted sovereign debt restructuring process and the fear of financial losses by economic agents. Simultaneously, the statements by policymakers of a Grexit had a large influence in expectations.

The second phase, from June 2012  to December 2014. Total deposits recovered slightly, in a total of 8.7 Billion Euros, and the economy was in a path of recovery by the second half of 2014.

The third phase, that started with the failure to elect the President and the general elections that led Syriza to power. The renewed fears of Grexit, failure to agree on the conclusion of the second program and the inability to instill confidence in the banking system led to a loss of deposits without precedent. From December 2014 to mid-June 2014 we estimate a total loss of 37.8 Billion Euros, at a monthly rate of 6.3 Billion Euros, more than double the speed of the first phase.

In total, Greece has lost 118.5 Billion Euros, almost half the amount it had in January 2009.

This is what distinguishes Greece from the other crisis countries: Ireland, Portugal and Spain.

To see the Figure press hereFigure Dep Greece

Advertisement

INNOVATION POLICIES FOR SMALLER EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

lab11

Innovation, considering the process of accumulation of intangible capital in a society, contributes with 20 to 30% to productivity growth in developed economies. Several European countries, including Portugal, have made a large effort in increasing its effort of State R&D. However, not only it only represents about 12% of the innovation effort, but its efficiency has been low. There is a need to increase the capability of the universities and large state laboratories to link with enterprises and increase the rate of patenting and creation of better products and markets and improve organizations. Based on an extensive array of best-practices around the world, the paper identifies a large spectrum of policies required to modernize universities, revitalize state laboratories and mainly launch a set of initiatives to increase innovation at enterprise level. This comprises building a decentralized network of design and technological centers closely linked to industry and services clusters, revitalizing cities and technological parks with incubators and financing of venture capital and start-ups. We identify a major role for multinationals in the process of upgrading to high-tech exports and inserting the country into the value-chains of global trade and ideas.Innovation Policies

Que caminhos para Portugal?

A8_NSAPMS2_large Com as eleições legislativas a aproximarem-se é tempo de se fazer uma reflexão sobre que questões o eleitorado colocará aos partidos políticos. As questões económicas que deveriam ser postas podem resumir-se em cinco: (i) que emprego se vai criar? (ii) qual a melhoria de rendimentos e salários? (iii) como se vai completar o programa de ajustamento e colocar a dívida pública numa trajetória sustentável? Os economistas mais esclarecidos e empresários irão perguntar: como se vão desalavancar as empresas portuguesas; e os trabalhadores e pensionistas: como restabelecr a credibilidade e sustentabilidade das pensões? Qualquer programa terá que respeitar a restrição orçamental para manter o acesso aos mercados financeiros e eventualmente levar a uma redução do risco da nossa dívida, o que só se consegue se sairmos em 2016 do grupo dos países com “défices excessivos” e se a recuperação do PIB se acentuar. Em termos de política orçamental propomos que se comece por reduzir os impostos mais distorcionários e só depois se expanda a despesa em áreas prioritárias, e sempre respeitando a necessidade de gerar um excedente primário de 1 a 2% do PIB. Depois de fazer um tour de horizon das propostas maiQue caminhos para Portugal r.2s recentes de política económica mais interessantes (na Alemanha, França e Espanha) a apresentação debruça-se sobre as três grandes áreas em que um programa económico se deve basear: (i) promover a competitividade da economia e a expansão dos transacionáveis, (ii) sustentar a desalavancagem das empresas criando mecanismos de reconversão da dívida, e de “limpeza dos balanços dos bancos”, e (iii) promover a inovação através da melhoria da eficiência do sistema de i&D, recentrá-lo na reconversão empresarial e na colaboração Universidades-Laboratórios-Empresas. Em todas estas áreas são feitas propostas concretas. Identificam-se também dois problemas estruturais básicos que são a necessidade de uma reforma constitucional para aproximar eleitores-eleitos e a responsabilização dos eleitos, assim como a qualidade das instituições políticas; e a reforma dos mecanismos de decisão das políticas governamentais, tomando por base as melhores práticas internacionais. Finalmente fazem-se algumas sugestões simples para melhorar a regulação e governação das empresas, e apontam-se alguns erros de análise graves que alguns economistas fizeram e continuam a fazer que têm trazido grandes custos para os portugueses. A apresentação pode ser lida aqui. Debate com um Grupo de Reflexão Estratégica em Lisboa a 24/4/2015.Que caminhos para Portugal r.2

Politicas de Estimulo da Oferta para Acelerar Potencial de Crescimento

Supply-side Policies for Increasing Growth Intervenção no Conselho da Industria Factory Merkel

Portugal está a sair do Programa de Ajustamento pelo que é fundamental reorientar a visão da Politica Economica de uma optica de curto para o longo prazo. Acabou a possibilidade de estimular apenas a Procura devido aos nossos elevados níveis de endividamento. A procura será estimulada pelo aumento da produção e criação de rendimento.

Por isso, é necessário que as políticas se virem para o estimulo à Oferta e crescimento da Produtividade Total dos Fatores. Entre os Países Desenvolvidos o fator Inovação contribui com cerca de um terço para o crescimento do PIB. Mas a política de Inovação não se reduz a financiar o I&D, mas é uma política mais vasta virada para a acumulação do “capital intangível” das empresas. Em Portugal o Estado já financia o I&D a níveis comparáveis à média europeia e temos um numero de investigadores per capita razoável, o problema é que temos o I&D mais ineficiente da Europa, se olharmos para os resultados na produtividade. É necessário uma nova estratégia de Inovação orientada para o desenvolvimento tecnológico a nível empresarial, maior entrosamento entre Universidades-Laboratórios e Empresas. É necessário criar centros de excelência de tecnologia e design a nível setorial-regional. Temos que reorientar os recursos do ensino superior para melhorar a sua performance e para darem uma resposta mais eficaz às necessidades da sociedade e economia. Temos que melhorar e estender o ensino dual e a aprendizagem.

Aqui ficam dois documentos sobre o tema. A nossa intervenção no Conselho da Industria de 2 de Fevereiro de 2015 e a apresentação de slides que a acompanha.Intervenção no Conselho da IndustriaSupply-side Policies for Increasing Growth

Deleveraging in a small economy of the euro

24olyclose-colorfire550

DELEVERAGING IN A SMALL ECONOMY OF THE EURO v.2

Deleveraging is essential for restoring financial sustainability and avoid recurring financial crisis. After one of the highest credit booms, Portugal as all Euro crisis countries is experiencing a substantial deleveraging of all economic agents, which limits GDP growth potential. The process only started in 2012 for enterprises and intensified for households, but is expected to be initiated in 2015 for the Public Sector. According to our estimates, in a base scenario, it will take up to 2030 for the economy to return to sustainable leverage ratios. In this scenario, enterprises will have to make most of the deleveraging until around 2020, while the public sector will take longer, with households already well in the way for stabilizing the debt ratios. The total debt ratio will have to be cut by 80 pp over 15 years, approaching the 2007 level. In a more stringent scenario, the overall debt over GDP will have to be cut by 130 pp, about the level of 2003, pre-crisis. Both these scenarios will impose a strong restriction on the expansion of the economy, which is expected to grow below its long-term historical path, and will require a major adjustment in corporate finance policies. We show that this challenge is of a heightened intensity than for the public sector. Finally, the paper summarizes policies can play a role in the deleveraging process.

FED supported much more massively banks than the Eurosystem and Bernanke on low interest rates

Bernanke has started a new blog at Brookings Institution that can be accessed here

http://www.brookings.edu/blogs/ben-bernanke/posts/2015/03/30-why-interest-rates-so-low?utm_campaign=Brookings+Brief&utm_source=hs_email&utm_medium=email&utm_content=16811230&_hsenc=p2ANqtz-_aFJNU9gwCpEuy3D7CMBfWO6rpyeuGQDqwtBFrYHmRpZvw6XwRiaAz8l_PJTgQtm3mNm0yAA37mnRzzi9PGeIfQhexqw&_hsmi=16811230

It is interesting the way that Bernanke justifies the policy of the FED (similar to the ECB and BoE) by reference to the “equilibrium interest rate”, a concept introduced by Wicksell at end of 19th century. Basically he argues that real interest rates need to be kept low to lift economies out of recession, over the medium term. What Bernanke has not yet answered is why long-term real interest rates have decreased since 1981: but he promises to do it in an upcoming blog.

In the Euro area short-term real interest rates were close to zero before the global financial crisis, increased to 1-2% during 2007 to 2009 and turned negative in the Euro crisis: -1% on average. Now they are again close to zero. The QE responds in large part to the preoccupation that deflation was increasing the real rates since mid-2013, as the figure attached shows Euro-interest rates.

But what Bernanke fails to show is the the dramatic increase in the FED interventions to support both the banks and US fiscal policy. This was unprecedented by any account.

Although interest rates are the transmission mechanism from monetary markets to the real sector, it is interesting also to measure the amounts of intervention of Central Banks.This analysis is rarely conducted by both Central Banks.

The attached file compares the balance sheets of the FED and the Eurosystem (ECB plus all Euro area Central Banks) FED and EUROSYSTEM INTERVENTIONS.To compare both systems we normalize by GDP.

Some pointers:

1- Interventions in money markets by the FED were much higher than the Eurosystem: the stock of Treasury securities and Asset Backed Securities was 24% of US GDP at end of 2014 compared with only 5% of the Eurozone.

2-Only in 2012, at the height of the Euro crisis the Eurosystem had an intervention close to the FED (10.5 against 17.1%).

3- The Quantitative Easing (Asset Purchasing Program) of 60 Billion Euros, to be implemented until September 2016, introduced by the ECB in March 2015, is just a drop in the ocean compared with the QE of the FED – it will increase holdings of Government securities to around 7% of GDP while the FED has holdings of 14%..

3-The balance sheet of the Eurosystem shows a much larger stock of gold and foreign reserves than the FED continuing to show the dominance of the Dollar as world currency.

In conclusion, the FED will have a much more difficult problem in winning out the US banks and Government than Euro zone countries.

THE EXPLOSION OF DOCTORAL DEGRESS IN PORTUGAL

graduation

 

Portugal had the largest increase in graduation rates at doctoral level among OECD countries in the last two decades, THE EXPLOSION OF DOCTORAL DEGREES IN PORTUGAL, and reached a position among the top rates in the last 4 years. This is odd when viewed in the context of most human resource and development indicators. This “inflation” of degrees was observed mainly in diplomas granted domestically, which represent about 90% of total, but also in degrees of Spanish universities. When decomposed by field of knowledge, there was a large decrease in the Exact and Natural Sciences and an increase in Humanities. The share of foreign graduates dropped significantly, which in part limits the improvement in the competence of faculties. Moreover, the number of Science and Technology and Economics and Management degrees given by foreign universities, which are crucial to increase the technological capabilities of the economy, has not increased in the last four decades. We identify some distortions in educational policies, make some brief recommendations and need of further research.

REFORMAS DO SISTEMA DE PENSÕES EM PORTUGAL: RESTABELECER O EQUILIBRIO ESTADO-MERCADO

As pensões em Portugal são baixas porque o nível de rendimento per capita é baixo. Porém, Portugal tem um dos sistemas mais ineficientes da OCDE, e em conjunto com a Itália as mais elevadas taxas de contribuição, o que põe em causa a competitividade do País. Este trabalho pretende identificar as deficiências mais flagrantes do nosso regime e propor soluções realistas, embora muitas tenham que ser graduais e de longo prazo. Daí a urgência das soluções. A maioria dos sistemas de pensões da OCDE combina instituições públicas e privadas, subsistemas obrigatórios e voluntários. Porém, em Portugal as visões contabilísticas de redução do défice orçamental têm levado à destruição das instituições privadas. Temos os pilares ocupacional e individual mais atrofiados da OCDE. Por outro lado, as medidas do Programa de Ajustamento comprometeram a credibilidade do sistema. É urgente repensar o sistema de pensões colocando-o em bases sólidas e que possam responder aos objetivos de um sistema moderno de pensões, com o reequilíbrio dos pilares ocupacional e individual. Sendo um instrumento fundamental para a redução da pobreza entre idosos, o sistema português tem uma das mais elevadas proporções de pensões de baixo rendimento na UE. É essencial que o sistema passe a incentivar a educação, a poupança e o investimento, contribuindo para restabelecer o crescimento da economia portuguesa e para o estancamento do “brain drain”

Para ler mais veja o trabalho:

. Reformas Segurança Social uma visão crítica

Estagnação e Colapso da Economia Portuguesa

Estudo interessante, que vale apena ler, sobre as origins da crise da economia, de Ricardo Reis, da Universidade de Columbia, em Nova York, e publicado em Março de 2013. Reis-Slump-Crash

The Slump and Crash of the Portuguese Economy

This is a study on the origins of the crisis of the Portuguese economy by Ricardo Reis of Columbia University worth reading, published in March 2013. Reis-Slump-Crash

Reis explains the slump in the Portuguese economy from 2000 to 2007 as a result of two shocks: (i) large capital inflows that followed the entry of Portugal into the Euro zone with the “underdeveloped” financial markets of the Portuguese economy, and (ii) the increase in taxes due to past commitments to old-age pensioners. He dismisses three other causes sometimes given for the slump: (a) trade shocks associated with the expansion of China, (b) discretionary state spending in goods and services, and (iii) labor market rigidity.

In our view, there was a boom after the entry of Portugal to the EU with large capital inflows that fuelled housing and general credit boom starting with the accession to the EU (1986), and ending in 2000. A model that captures the boom was built by Fagan and Gaspar (see footnote 2). The boom was also fed by large expenditures taken or sponsored by the state. All indebtedness levels increased dramatically in 1986-2000. The stop of the real estate boom and the high level of household level led to a stagnation in consumption and house investment after 2000. The slump was seriously aggravated by a massive misallocation in the continuing capital inflows channeled to nontrabales with low productivity (construction of infrastructure and other state sponsored expenditures as well as retail and wholesale trade). Why? The main reason was that they were sheltered from international competition, regulated with secured high margins or the loans were guaranteed by the state (zero weight in the solvability ratio of banks). The sudden stop that started with Greece and then extended to Ireland and Portugal was a result of the heightened awareness by investors of the levels of indebtedness in these economies and the threat that they would not be able to pay their debts.

Our main criticism of the paper is that the periodization that Reis adopts is arbitrary, and to better comprehend what really happened in the country we should extend the analysis at least to the 1990s. In this case, the traditional model of boom and slump of large capital inflows explains most of the facts. Presenting rates of change of several indicators starting in 2000 without a judgment about its levels can lead to erroneous interpretations.

Another common mistake is to say that there was no housing boom in Portugal. Using AMECO data, Spain had a boom in 1999 to 2008 with the accumulated investment in dwellings over GDP of 77%, Ireland had a boom in 1998 to 2008 with 113%, and Portugal had a boom in 1987 to 1999 with 89%. In all cases the investment ratio collapsed after the boom to levels below the pre-boom numbers. Most commentators use house prices to document the cycle, but there are no reliable price statistics to follow these phenomena, at least for Portugal. When the house construction boom stopped in Portugal there were about 400 thousand houses unoccupied (for a 10 million population).

Reis builds a model with two sectors: tradables and nontradables. Credit is allocated to the nontradables sector through the banking sector that collects funds domestically and abroad and allocates them subject to collateral constraints, typical of a financial frictions model. Because capital is misallocated and taxes increase, the exchange rate appreciates and the nontradables sector expands with the economy slumping. Otherwise there would be a boom like in Ireland and Italy.

Capital inflows resulted from the reduction in the risk premium to the economy. The large inflows from North to South Europe (plus Ireland) were a Euro phenomenon, not specific to Portugal. The differentiation of risk across Euro countries is yet not well understood. A number of policy makers from these countries continue to insist that interest rates for all Euro countries should be the same (common currency area). If short term interest rates in money markets should be similar, credit rates should reflect the risk and liquidity associated with each debtor. Thus, a government bond of a high debt state should have a higher risk premium. The inverse that prevailed from around 1997 to 2008 is abnormal.

The author proposes some evidence, based on TFP estimates of the KLEMS data base, that there was misallocation of resources because the sectors that expanded (community services, real estate and wholesale and retail trade) had the largest decrease in TFP and rising markups. But all sectors show a decrease in TFP: the misallocation was more widespread. E.g. the high rents in energy and telecommunications was documented by the Portuguese Competition Authority. Our book “Economia Portuguesa” gives evidence of the extremely low rates of return of the PPPs.

Both in Greece (with the Olympics of 2004)[1] and Portugal (with the World Expo of 1998 and Euro soccer championship of 2004) there were also large public expenditures with evidence of high costs and low returns. See “Economia Portuguesa” (chapter 11) for evidence.

The role attributed to tax increase seems overplayed since the ratio of taxes over GDP only increased by 1.7% in 2000-2007. It also looks overplayed the increase in 3.3% of the pensions of old-age. More important was the increase in discretionary spending through the public enterprises and infrastructure construction (Mateus A., Boom and a Long Slump in a Small Economy of the Euro Zone: the Portuguese case, 2012[2]). The author refers “en passant” the role of PPPs saying that the impact on public debt will come in the future. But here we study real economy impacts (not financial flows) and the impact of these investments was high. The numbers in this table are difficult to ignore (from Mateus above):

Table 4: Total Public Investment (GFCF in percent GDP)

  1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2008
In the budget 2.5 3.0 3.8 3.8 3.3 2.2
PPPs 0.0 0.0 1.2 3.5 7.0 12.6
   Total 2.5 3.0 5.0 7.3 10.3 14.8

Source: INE, National Accounts and author’s estimates

On labor market rigidity the author argues that the marginal worker affected by the slump is a fixed-term contract which is quite flexible. According to Reis, the permanent contracts of the average worker are substantially rigid but they contribute to the (level!) of low productivity of labor force in the country. However, the contribution of this factor vis-à-vis others like the low level of human capital needs to be investigated.

The literature on sudden stops of capital inflows explain a boom in consumption followed by a crash, but the country did not have a consumption boom in the 2000-2007 period. AS we documented above, both levels of consumption and construction in housing (particularly stock of houses) were quite high in the starting year, thus, the increases afterwards were modest. From 1986 (date of entry to the EU) to 2000 private consumption increased at an average annual rate of 7% compared with 1.4% in the 2001-2007 period. Similarly, public consumption also increased much faster in that period (4.3% against 1.4% in the 2001-2007). The large investment in housing was fuelled by the large increase in household indebtedness (debt over disposable income increased 4.2 times to 77%, and further to 114% in 2010).[3] In fact, it was common for Central Bank and governments of the late 1990s up to the crisis to dismiss the existence of any disequilibria saying that that indebtedness had a counterbalance in the raising assets of households and that external deficits did not matter in the context of the Euro area. We think that a better story is the traditional boom slump model, with a long delayed bust (should the sudden stop not have happened already at the beginning of the 21st century?) and the sudden stop was delayed to after the global crisis of 2007-2009, like in the other Euro crisis countries.

There are systemic and idiosyncratic factors for the Euro and Portuguese crisis. Reis models some specific factors that contributed to the slump. It is particularly interesting in Reis model that the low net worth of Portuguese firms deepened the slump. Similarly, it would be an increase in net worth that would lead the country out of the crisis. The same would need to happen in the household sector. The problem is how net worth will increase since it is clearly an endogenous variable.

The existence of a large mass of inefficient firms in operation in all sectors of the economy and the financial constraint on other small and medium enterprises that operate below the optimal scale because of lack of collateral for borrowing is attributed to underdeveloped capital markets. These characteristics of the Portuguese statistical distributions of enterprises are well known, but we think that the reasons for these distributions are also due to lack of labor and capital mobility, as well as typical family enterprises in developing economies. We also think that bureaucratic, regulatory and fiscal factors (a la Sotto) linked with informality are crucial to explain those distributions.

Is the credit channel to SMEs really that important to explain the slump? Let us look at the distribution of loans by use. Comparing credit allocation by sectors in 2007 compared with 2000 there was a 10 pp increase in the share of construction and real estate, and 6 pp in manufacturing and 4 pp in trade. It confirms the movement away from tradables, but not for the expanding sectors he identifies. Those movements were even more pronounced if we compare 2010 with 1987 with a decrease of 28 pp in manufacturing and increase of 21 pp in construction and real estate, which is consistent with the housing boom of 1987-2000 magnified with the infrastructure and other public sector expansion in the same period and intensified in 2000-2010.

According to Reis the crux of the matter was that the massive capital inflows in the Euro area were intermediated by the banking sector into inefficient firms in the nontradable sector. But there is even no increase in output and employment in nontradables because the raise in taxes leads to a fall in supply of labor. Is most of the increased in unemployment due to the destruction of firms lacking demand/credit/competitiveness or because workers do not want to work as hard (the supply side effect)? The author distinguishes the Portuguese economy from Greece, Spain and Ireland stating that it has a more undeveloped capital market, an assumption which we question. First, Greece never had an intermediation level similar to Portugal, and Spain had a similar financial system. The Irish market is clearly more developed due to the influence of the City of London and the large presence of multinationals, but instead of searching for some structural factors it can be simply argued that the housing boom was a decade later in the cases of Spain and Ireland, relative to Portugal, and that the expansion of the state sector as well as the state sponsored projects were larger in the case of Greece and Portugal. Moreover, there were also large capital inflows in the 1990s to Portugal, if the same structural characteristics prevailed in the economy, why there was a boom and not a slump?

This is an interesting work that represents a serious work for rationalizing the slump of the Portuguese economy and worth studying in detail. It makes a contribution to the study of capital market imperfections and its macroeconomic impact. But we think that the origins of the crisis in Southern states should be searched in political economy, combined with risk misperception factors that are common to a number of financial crisis (not alone the 2007 global crisis).

Two external factors

Portugal entered the Euro with the first group of countries – the founding members. The exchange rate had been almost fixed since 1994, but the irrevocable rates were determined in about one year previous to the start, although the last rates (rounded to the last digit) were determined in the eve of January 1st, 1999. These were the years of the peak of the credit and investment boom, culminating in the Expo of 1998. The last priority of the government was to question the exchange rate of entry, although this was a major decision for the country. But there were two clear signs of overvaluation. The first was the climb in unit labor costs since the late 1980s, the second was the increasing current account deficit.[4] According to our estimates we entered with about a 10-15% overvaluation.[5] This was very serious because it was a once for all effect. Reis dismisses this factor in the slump of the first decade of the 21st century, saying that the economy would have adjusted. However, it is not quite that easy. It is right if we have a fully flexible model with rational expectations. However, there are important rigidities in the product and labor markets well known by economists that will make the adjustment long and generates significant unemployment in the medium term. This adjustment was delayed because of the discretionary investment and current expenditures sponsored or undertaken by the state, plus the continuing capital inflows. Just to refer one rigidity: the collective bargaining of wages that take place still nowadays in large sectors, with a zero bound nominal wage change. Since inflation rates were quite low, it was difficult for real wages to adjust. It is interesting that there were other mechanism at work to adjust the labor market. In the 1990s there was a large influx of illegal emigrants from Eastern Europe (mainly Ukraine and Moldova), and also from Portuguese speaking Africa, probably in the order of tens of thousands, a large part to the construction sector. These flows reverse themselves in 2000-2010 period as labor market conditions deteriorated relative to the originating economies.

Another important factor was the enlargement of the EU to Eastern Europe that coincided with globalization, rise of China in world markets and liberalization of trade in textiles. Reis also dismisses this factor because it affected also other countries that did not have the slump. However, if we believe that there are rigidities in capital and labor markets, capital is immobile in the short to medium term, and it takes time for labor to readapt its skills, then the shock that started in the 1990s would reverberate throughout the 2000-decade. All estimates done of the impact of the enlargement to the East pointed to Portugal as the country that would lose more (See Economia Portuguesa the chapters on integration and spatial economy). One example was the automobile sector. When Ford-Volkswagen signed the contract for building a factory of Auto-Europa in the late 1980s the plans were to produce 400 thousand vehicles. When it started to operate in the 1990s it never went above 150 thousand. I still remember a conversation with the head of the research of the Central Bank of Austria telling me around 1994 that Auto-Europa would be the last automobile factory built in Portugal. Most of the future investment in this sector would take place in the square of Czech Republic, Slovakia and Hungary because of agglomeration economies, proximity to the German markets and availability of skilled labor at low wages. He was right.

What is the relative contribution of the capital inflows, discretionary spending by the state, overvaluation of exchange rates and value chains in FD? It is difficult to disentangle. That is way we need general equilibrium models, preferably dynamic and with some disaggregation, in the footsteps of Reis contribution.

 

 

Abel Mateus

April, 21st, 2014

 

 

 

[1] The Olympic park and staging of the games cost 9 Billion Euros (Bloomberg Business Week, August 2012). A new airport (a PPP with the state and German construction companies) and metro system linking the airport to the city were also built, to a total cost of about 20-30 Billion Euros, equivalent to 10 to 15% of GDP. Greece also carried out a large road construction program: they absorbed about 60% of the structural funds.

[2] Please see some of our papers on the Social Science Research Network (SSRN) at:  http://ssrn.com/author=1223260.

[3] A model capturing the boom was built by Fagan and Gaspar, Adjusting to the Euro Area: Some Issues inspired by the Portuguese Experience, European Central Bank, 2005. See our comments on this paper in Economia Portuguesa, pg 382.

[4] The deficit was dismissed as relevant by the authorities because we were in a currency union, (who bothers about the deficit of Texas or Alabama? Was frequently said by the highest officials) and because changes in statistical methodologies obscured the right numbers.

[5] It is difficult to disentangle the impact of the excess credit growth in that number.